acm-header
Sign In

Communications of the ACM

Communications of the ACM

Digital Village: Predatory Disintermediation


disintermediation (dis-,int-er-,med-e-′a-shen) n. Withdrawal of funds from intermediary financial institutions, such as banks and savings and loan associations, in order to invest in instruments yielding a higher return.

This definition comes from the electronic version of the Third Edition (1994) American Heritage Dictionary, and it gives an idea of just how fast things change in cyberspace. Once a reserved word within the banking community, the term "disintermediation" has now spread well beyond even the broader financial industry. In its current use, it applies to any and all contexts where one "eliminates the middleman." Such an environment is said to be disintermediated. Of particular importance is its near-ubiquitous role in e-commerce—at the level of transaction, distribution system, supply chain, customer service, customer management, and so forth.

In its new manifestation, disintermediation covers a lot of ground. In the most positive sense, disintermediation extends the notion of adding value to commerce. Any electronic, computer-based, or network technology that reduces transaction friction or shrinks the trading distance qualifies. What harm could there be in using Internet resources to establish closer and more immediate and personal connectivity between provider and consumer?

I foresee a great deal of harm resulting from disintermediation that becomes predatory. In this sense, the purpose of the disintermediation migrates away from the concept of adding value and establishing closer links with customers, toward the destruction of another value-added industry.

Back to Top

Symbiotic Disintermediation

Were this a perfect world, all disintermediation would be symbiotic. A supplier might have difficulty reaching beyond a current customer base. A distributor comes forth who, for a reasonable percentage of the profits, will open up the supplier to an entirely new world of potential customers. The supplier, of course, makes a bit less on each transaction, but that's more than made up for by the increase in sales volume. The disintermediator—the innovative distributor in this case—adds value to the commerce by simultaneously connecting consumers who were beyond the commercial reach of the supplier with the products they need, and strengthening the marketing capability of the supplier. With symbiosis, whether disintermediated or of the Tobriand Island variety, everyone comes out ahead.

A modern example of symbiotic disintermediation is Amazon.com. The added value Amazon.com brought to the table was primarily convenience and facilitation, and, secondarily, supplier-independence. It provided a convenient, electronic platform for shopping, reducing the transaction friction of book purchases by using the concept of "virtual inventory." One needn't meander through the warm, wooden canyons of a Barnes and Noble store to find that perfect tome for a special occasion—one could achieve the same result (sans Starbucks) by electronically navigating through Amazon.com's virtual bookstore. Further, by maintaining a virtual inventory, Amazon.com avoids the concomitant overhead of a full-service bookseller. When customers pay for the contents of their virtual shopping cart with a credit card, they buy a promissory note agreeing that Amazon.com would find suppliers somewhere in the world to provide the contents at an agreed-upon price. After all, whether an inventory is virtual or veridical is irrelevant so long as the consumer gets the book on time and as promised.

The concept is exceedingly symbiotic: Amazon.com provides a very useful service that was previously unavailable, namely the electronic facilitation of the book-purchase transaction, and in exchange, receives a fee. Just the same, the supplier (the book publishers in this case) are more than willing to pay the fee for the opportunity to reach an untapped customer base—the online book buyer. Or are they? We'll return to this in a moment.

Another example of disintermediation is the presence of online security brokerages that have become increasingly popular. Once again, the Internet provides the infrastructure for convenient disintermediation. The customer is no longer tethered to the intermediary agent's office, fax, or phone, but is free to deal directly with the brokerage—the entity seated on the exchange that is authorized and empowered to buy and sell equities on behalf of others. In this way, a new virtual community of online day traders evolved.

It is interesting to note this "Internet zaibatsu" of the late 1990s first focused our attention on the economic consequences of successful disintermediation. The widespread popularity of online brokerages was almost exclusively due to investor cost-savings. Investors were drawn quickly to the online brokerages because the value of traditional broker services was perceived to be incommensurate with their fee structure. Commerce common sense dictates that in a free and open market, the health, security, and long-term survivability of a service is directly related to the perceived value of that service. Without the security of protected transaction portals to the stock exchanges, traditional brokers became excess baggage to those attracted to online investing. Hence, cost-savings became a sufficient motivation to cut the traditional broker out of the transaction loop. As a consequence, online brokerages proliferated beyond levels justified by need and common sense, ironically as their shrinking margins undercut their own viability. The two economic insights gained were that disintermediation may have a devastating impact on traditional service industries and that many can play this game.

The most important lesson to be learned from the Internet zaibatsu is my First Principle of Symbiotic Disintermediation: When the advantage of the disintermediation is predicated upon parsimony, economies of scale, or the novel use of a publicly accessible technology infrastructure, one cannot create formidable barriers to effective competition. Failure to take heed of this principle will in the end cause more fortunes to be lost in e-commerce than are made. This lesson also extends easily to other sectors of the economy. While the financial sector may have been the first proving ground of this postulate, the service and manufacturing sectors follow in close succession, and from all appearances, aren't learning much from past misjudgments.

This brings us back to our paradigm case of symbiotic disintermediation—Amazon.com. While the disintermediation is indeed symbiotic, it cannot be sustainable since it clearly violates our First Principle. Amazon.com's movement into other media venues (CDs, DVD and video, auctions, and so forth), does not ameliorate the situation, rather it extends the violation of the First Principle over a broader range of product offerings. Therein lies the inherent flaw in the basic Amazon.com concept. The value-added convenience—economy and supplier-independence—is easily replicable. Thus, we would have predicted from the onset that it should be impossible to preserve a competitive advantage for the first-to-market provider. Quite to the contrary, a corollary to the First Principle is that the very success of the online disintermediation encourages those higher in the economic food chain to go online themselves (for example, Barnes and Noble added barnesandnoble.com). This, ironically, gives the disintermediator's competitor the advantage because they actually own and control their own inventories. So, based upon the First Principle and its corollary, one would have predicted from the onset there would be immediate and threatening competition to Amazon.com from their own suppliers and vendors. And this is exactly what happened—the disintermediator is getting disintermediated.

Table. A Cost Benefit Comparison. Using the Web reservation services to a car.


First Principle of Symbiotic Disintermediation: When the advantage of the disintermediation is predicated upon parsimony, economies of scale, or the novel use of a publicly accessible technology infrastructure, one cannot create formidable barriers to effective competition.


There is another feature of Amazon.com that is also worth noting leading us to my Second Principle of Symbiotic Disintermediation: An instance of symbiotic disintermediation can only reach stability and maintain viability if the value added is proprietary, inherently unique, difficult to replicate, or legally protected. Amazon.com made a gesture in this direction with its semi-moderated or unmoderated database of online reviews, the implementation of which remains half-hearted and uninspiring. For related discussion about adding value to publications, see "Value-Added Publishing" ("Digital Village," Jan. 1999).

The only area in which these first two principles break down is in market capitalization. There seems to be an abiding confidence amongst e-commerce investors that an unsound business plan will improve with age. It reminds me of a sign I saw once in a local shop that read "While we lose a little money on each sale, we make up for it in volume."

Back to Top

Uninspired Symbiotic Disintermediation

In an ideal world, disintermediation would always be symbiotic. However, there are examples for which the actual case for added value is tenuous. One example is the rental car Web reservation system, where it is not always clear whether the experience better illustrates value-adding or time-sinking.

For purposes of this column, during my family vacation last summer, I conducted a cost-benefit experiment. The hypothesis to be tested was that I could use the Web reservation services to save money for a rental car compared to the rates provided by my travel agent. The control group was my travel agent. The experimental group was me armed with the set of rental car Web reservation sites. The measurement is travel agent-obtained rates vs. Web-obtained rates plus "transaction cost," which is the value of the typical customer's time spent on finding the lowest rates.

We set out to compare rental rates for a minivan, rented in Ft. Lauderdale on May 10, 1999 and returned there on May 17, 1999. For purposes of calculating the transaction cost for this activity, I recorded our charges in an activity log (see the table "A Cost Benefit Comparison"). Assuming an average annual customer income of $60,000, with approximately 2,000 hours in a work-year, that comes to $30/hour or 50 cents/minute for customer time. Times shown represent transaction times for specified activities.

There are other details that figure into the timing of the activity that I haven't included for the sake of brevity. Among them are: (1) a host of "security alert" prompts that required frequent bypassing, (2) sundry other distracting, warning prompts that chewed up time, (3) an occasional cookie invitation that needed to be declined, (4) correction of typing errors (assume in my experiment customers are perfect typists), (5) the fact that the salary level is below national averages for those likely to subscribe to Communications, and, finally, (6) I stopped the search at the first hint of success without even trying to make comparisons to find the best value. Against this, I contrasted the situation where I turned the entire process over to a travel agent. Result: the same fare without any involvement beyond an initial, verbal query. Overhead as a percentage of rental rate: 1%.

The moral: in symbiotic disintermediation on the Web, along with every other aspect of human activity, not everything that we can do is worth doing. In my case, the use of the Web reservation services for automobile rental was far from cost-effective.

Back to Top

Predatory Disintermediation

Up to this point, I have only discussed symbiotic disintermediation where the disintermediator attempts to complement an existing commercial activity. Overall, one expects a win-win. Such is not the case with predatory disintermediation, which is potentially the most dangerous dimension of disintermediation on the Internet.

Reconsider the situation of the traditional stockbroker. The disintermediator, the online brokerage service, seeks to compete for the same pool of investment resources as the traditional broker. It capitalizes on the public's perception that the fee-for-service rate of the stockbroker is excessive. However, and this is a critical point, online brokers and traditional brokers are competitors in the truest sense, and neither has a de facto or de jure competitive advantage over the other.

Now let's change the situation somewhat. Suppose that instead of the traditional brokerages versus online brokerages, we compare two online brokerages with the following twist: one of the online brokerages is owned by the stock exchange itself. Now the playing field becomes uneven. There is certainly a strong, potential advantage to the online brokerage owned by the stock exchange. Consider the trivial case where both brokerages seek to acquire the same available shares of stock. Since the stock exchange acts as the clearinghouse the stock is passed through their own online brokerage first as the shares become available.

Impossible, you say? Actually there is disintermediation not totally dissimilar on the Internet today: airline reservation systems.

Most modern airlines have their own reservation Web sites. Services such as those found on United Airline's Web site (Figures 1 and 2) are in widespread use. From the point of view of disintermediation, all seems innocuous enough. However, travel agents report quite another story. The fact is the disintermediation gives the appearance of being predatory because it violates the unspoken requirement of symbiotic disintermediation, namely that there be a level playing field.

Consider that the airline-owned reservation services sell the airline's own product (just like the exchange-owned brokerages). This gives them an enormous advantage over competitive disintermediators. For one, they can offer special fares and perks exclusively to their online customers (remember, airfares are unregulated). Second, through their own proprietary reservation databases, they control the blocking and releasing of seat assignments on their aircraft; online customers could receive preferential treatment. Third, they make their own rules with respect to ticket refunds, penalties, and the conditions under which tickets may be exchanged that may or may not be consistently offered to customers of other reservation systems. Fourth, they control the way upgrades and frequent traveler rewards are handled, so other agents may not be able to provide passengers the same level of assurance that the upgrades and rewards will be honored. Fifth, they may not provide the same level of customer service support to those who hold foreign tickets. But worst of all, from the consumer's point of view, the pricing model of the airline's internal reservation system is positive for them, neutral for the passengers, and negative for outside agents. That is, the model produces additional revenue for the airlines rather than fare discounts to the customer equal to any travel agent's commissions saved.

Remember, the online brokerages are not predatory in this sense because none of them own or control the stocks they sell—that's handled by a presumably impartial and even-handed stock exchange. It may be worth mentioning that it was not claimed in the recent NASDAQ class action litigation that the NASDAQ market makers gave preferential treatment to particular brokerage houses. Rather, it was argued they defrauded investors equally, without regard to race, color, creed, or favored broker.

Airline reservation systems are another matter entirely. Their business model appears to leverage unfair ticketing advantages at the expense of external agents and rival disintermediators. Presently, airlines have slashed travel agent's commissions to the point where in order to survive agents need to add a surcharge to the price of the ticket (which, of course, ensures they operate at a competitive disadvantage). From my perspective as a frequent traveler, it appears as though the business plan of the airline's proprietary reservation systems includes the elimination of the travel agent. Whether or not this was their intention, cutting travel agents' commissions is having this effect. Travel agents have an important role in maintaining low-fare competition.


Second Principle of Symbiotic Disintermediation: An instance of symbiotic disintermediation can only reach stability and maintain viability if the value added is proprietary, inherently unique, difficult to replicate, or legally protected.


Of course, to a great degree, one's position on just how worrisome predatory disintermediation is depends on one's perception of the value added by the intermediate service. Online brokerages caught on quickly because of the public perception that the traditional broker contributed little value to the transaction. However, as a frequent traveler I view the travel agent as a classic case of a value-adding reseller. When a flight is canceled, my first choice is not to seek reaccommodation from the carrier that cancelled the flight. My travel agent and I both agree that "optimal routing" does not include a carrier's hub which is 500 miles further away from my destination than my departing city. My travel agent takes into account the reliability and on-time arrival/departure frequency of regional carriers before selecting a parent carrier, and understands the value of booking originating flights. My travel agent understands that while a 45-minute connection in Dallas/Ft. Worth between Atlantic Southeast and an American Airlines international flight is a legal connection, it's probably not an intelligent one. I don't rely on the airline that destroyed the contents of my luggage to outline my options or provide me with the contact information for the appropriate complaint office of the FAA. Finally, I have the confidence that when my travel agent reports a lowest available fare, it is.

E-commerce is forcing us to revisit many core business issues, from the construction of a viable business model to the privacy and security of a transaction, many of which were a given just a few years ago. One of these core business issues is the nature and effect of disintermediation, and the role it plays in e-commerce. One of the most fascinating dimensions of disintermediation is the cavalier approach we take toward predicting its viability—as reflected in the totally off-the-wall market capitalizations of companies that have never, and may never, generate any profit. But equally fascinating, although far more worrisome to me, is the potentially disastrous social and economic consequences of disintermediation of a predatory or parasitic nature.

Of course when one argues such a point, one risks being labeled a post-modern Luddite. If I am right, however, the technology of disintermediation is not to be feared, but rather the possibility that it may be intentionally used to eliminate or stifle competition. While no one could deny that the automobile industry drove the horse-drawn carriage and buggy-whip industry out of business, the consequence was a by-product of the industry and not its objective. Parallels may be drawn with the digital watch and chronometer industries, and between television and radio. But in the era of digital disintermediation, the potential abuses are more widespread and the social consequences more immediate and much greater.

It might also be claimed that what I've been calling predatory disintermediation is really nothing more than direct-to-customer wholesaling—the 21st century analogue to the factory outlet mall. While I admit to the conceptual similarity, the potential impact of disintermediation is far greater because of the geographical transparency of the transaction medium. In principle, there was never anything prohibiting manufacturers from directly competing with their retailers and suppliers (except perhaps common sense), but it was a practical impossibility. Consider that even today the proliferation of factory outlet malls has not significantly diminished the availability of the brand-name products through traditional retail channels. The same would not be true if there were an outlet mall across the street from every retail store. This is where there's a practical difference. Digital disintermediation makes it possible to compete with every retail outlet with a virtual outlet mall across the street. For those of us who see the value in value-added retailing, this is a serious concern on equal footing with monopolistic practices, predatory pricing, and restraint of trade.

Back to Top

Author

Hal Berghel is professor and chair of Computer Science at the University of Nevada, at Las Vegas and a frequent contributor to the literature on cyberspace. His cyber-residence is www.acm.org/hlb.

Back to Top

Figures

F1Figure 1. United Airlines Web site.

F2Figure 2. Online fare listing for United flights.

Back to Top

Tables

UT1Table. A Cost Benefit Comparison. Using the Web reservation services to a car.

Back to top


©2000 ACM  0002-0782/00/0800  $5.00

Permission to make digital or hard copies of all or part of this work for personal or classroom use is granted without fee provided that copies are not made or distributed for profit or commercial advantage and that copies bear this notice and the full citation on the first page. To copy otherwise, to republish, to post on servers or to redistribute to lists, requires prior specific permission and/or a fee.

The Digital Library is published by the Association for Computing Machinery. Copyright © 2000 ACM, Inc.


 

No entries found